19.2 Semi-random Experiment

Chicago Open Enrollment Program (Cullen, Jacob, and Levitt 2005)

  • Students can apply to “choice” schools

  • Many schools are oversubscribed (Demand > Supply)

  • Resolve scarcity via random lotteries

  • Non-random enrollment, we only have random lottery which mean the above

Let

\[ \delta_j = E(Y_i | Enroll_{ij} = 1; Apply_{ij} = 1) - E(Y_i | Enroll_{ij} = 0; Apply_{ij} = 1) \]

and

\[ \theta_j = E(Y_i | Win_{ij} = 1; Apply_{ij} = 1) - E(Y_i | Win_{ij} = 0; Apply_{ij} = 1) \]

Hence, we can clearly see that \(\delta_j \neq \theta_j\) because you can only enroll, but you cannot ensure that you will win. Thus, intention to treat is different from treatment effect.

Non-random enrollment, we only have random lottery which means we can only estimate \(\theta_j\)

To recover the true treatment effect, we can use

\[ \delta_j = \frac{E(Y_i|W_{ij} = 1; A_{ij} = 1) - E(Y_i | W_{ij}=0; A_{ij} = 1)}{P(Enroll_{ij} = 1| W_{ij}= 1; A_{ij}=1) - P(Enroll_{ij} = 1| W_{ij}=0; A_{ij}=1)} \]

where

  • \(\delta_j\) = treatment effect

  • \(W\) = Whether students win the lottery

  • \(A\) = Whether student apply for the lottery

  • i = application

  • j = school

Say that we have

10 win

Number students Type Selection effect Treatment effect Total effect
1 Always Takers +0.2 +1 +1.2
2 Compliers 0 +1 +1
7 Never Takers -0.1 0 -0.1

10 lose

Number students Type Selection effect Treatment effect Total effect
1 Always Takers +0.2 +1 +1.2
2 Compliers 0 0 0
7 Never Takers -0.1 0 -0.1

Intent to treatment = Average effect of who you give option to choose

\[ \begin{aligned} E(Y_i | W_{ij}=1; A_{ij} = 1) &= \frac{1*(1.2)+ 2*(1) + 7 * (-0.1)}{10}\\ &= 0.25 \end{aligned} \]

\[ \begin{aligned} E(Y_i | W_{ij}=0; A_{ij} = 1) &= \frac{1*(1.2)+ 2*(0) + 7 * (-0.1)}{10}\\ &= 0.05 \end{aligned} \]

Hence,

\[ \begin{aligned} \text{Intent to treatment} &= 0.25 - 0.05 = 0.2 \\ \text{Treatment effect} &= 1 \end{aligned} \]

\[ \begin{aligned} P(Enroll_{ij} = 1 | W_{ij} = 1; A_{ij}=1 ) &= \frac{1+2}{10} = 0.3 \\ P(Enroll_{ij} = 1 | W_{ij} = 0; A_{ij}=1 ) &= \frac{1}{10} = 0.1 \end{aligned} \]

\[ \text{Treatment effect} = \frac{0.2}{0.3-0.1} = 1 \]

After knowing how to recover the treatment effect, we turn our attention to the main model

\[ Y_{ia} = \delta W_{ia} + \lambda L_{ia} + e_{ia} \]

where

  • \(W\) = whether a student wins a lottery

  • \(L\) = whether student enrolls in the lottery

  • \(\delta\) = intent to treat

Hence,

  • Conditional on lottery, the \(\delta\) is valid

  • But without lottery, your \(\delta\) is not random

  • Winning and losing are only identified within lottery

  • Each lottery has multiple entries. Thus, we can have within estimator

We can also include other control variables (\(X_i \theta\))

\[ Y_{ia} = \delta_1 W_{ia} + \lambda_1 L_{ia} + X_i \theta + u_{ia} \]

\[ \begin{aligned} E(\delta) &= E(\delta_1) \\ E(\lambda) &\neq E(\lambda_1) && \text{because choosing a lottery is not random} \end{aligned} \]

Including \((X_i \theta)\) just shifts around control variables (i.e., reweighting of lottery), which would not affect your treatment effect \(E(\delta)\)

References

Cullen, Julie Berry, Brian A Jacob, and Steven D Levitt. 2005. “The Impact of School Choice on Student Outcomes: An Analysis of the Chicago Public Schools.” Journal of Public Economics 89 (5-6): 729–60.