36.2 Product Adoption and Diffusion

36.2.1 Background

  • Every new thing either diffuses through population or fails

  • Researchers are interested in the shape and processes of diffusion

  • Bass is the first to model in marketing

Diffusion in different fields:

  • Demography

  • Archaeology

  • Geography

  • Epidemiology

  • Sociology

  • Linguistics

  • Physics

  • Cosmology

Models of Diffusion

  • Negative Exponential

  • Bass

  • FDA

  • Network

Levels of analysis:

  • Class:

  • Category

  • Technology

  • Brand

Classic model

  • does not account fro marketing mix

  • requires peak sales for stable estimates (if you have the peaks, you don’t need the model)

  • no repurscrhsases

  • no multiple generation

  • does not fit viral patterns

36.2.1.1 (Chandrasekaran and Tellis 2007) A review of new products diffusion

  • Products = idea, person, good, or service

  • New product \(\neq\) innovation

In econ In marketing
Diffusion “the spread of an innovation across social groups over time (p. 39) “the communication of an innovation through the population”
Phenomenon (spread of a product) \(\neq\) drivers (communication) Phenomenon (spread of a product) = driver (communication)

This paper focuses on the econ definition

Product’s life cycle stages:

  1. Commercialization: when the product was first sold
  2. Takeoff: dramatic and sustained increase in sales
  3. Introduction: between commercialization and takeoff
  4. Slowdown: decreasing in sales
  5. Growth: between takeoff and slowdown
  6. Maturity: Slowdown until decline.

Generalizations:

  • Shape of the Diffusion Curve: cumulative sales over time is S-shaped curve.

  • Parameters of the Bass model:

    • Coefficient of innovation or external influence (\(p\))

      • mean between 0.0007 and 0.03

      • mean for developed countries is 0.001 and developing countries is 0.0003

    • Coefficient of imitation or internal influence (\(q\))

      • mean between 0.38 and 0.53

      • industrial/medical innovation > consumer durables

      • 0.51 for developed countries and 0.56 for developing countries

    • the market potential (\(\alpha\) or \(m\))

      • 0.52 for developed countries and 0.17 for developing countries.
  • Cautions regarding the parameters:

    • Time to peak sales: 19 years for developing and 16 for developed countries.

    • Biases in parameter estimation: static models (e.g., Bass) lead to downward biases in market potential and innovation while upward bias in imitation.

  • Drivers: WOM, communication, economics, marketing mix variables (e.g., prices, consumer heterogeneity, consumer learning), purchasing power parity adjusted per capita income, international trade.

  • Turning points of the diffusion curve

    • Takeoff

      • Time to takeoff: 6-10 years (varies by countries,products, time).

      • Drivers: price decrease

    • Slowdown

      • Sales decline by 15-32%

      • Drivers: price decline, market penetration, wealth (GNP), and info cascades (fast takeoff = fast decline)

  • Findings across stages

    • Duration:

      • introduction: 6-10 years

      • growth: 8-10 years

      • early maturity: 5 years

      • duration of growth:

        • time saving products > non-time saving products

        • leisure enhancing products < non-leisure enhancing products

      • introduction and early maturity duration get shorter over time (but not growth)

    • Price: price reduction is getting larger as time progresses (for both introduction nd growth).

    • Growth rates:

      • Introduction: 31%

      • Takeoff: 428%

      • Growth: 45%

      • Slowdown: -15%

      • Early maturity: -25%

      • Late maturity: 3.7%

Future Research:

  • Measurement: When to start or stop, or takeoff, differentiation between first purchases and repurchases, demand is better than supply measure,

  • Theories: no reconciliation yet

  • Models: comprehensive (from commercialization to takeoff, growth, and slowdown)

  • Findings: More fine-tune subgroups, include failed diffusion, and consider other countries.

Specification

The probability that an individual will purchase at time \(T\) is a function of the number of previous buyers.

\[ P(t) = \frac{f(t)}{1 - F(t)} = p + \frac{q}{m} Y(t) \]

where

  • \(P(t)\) = hazard rate

  • \(Y(t)\) = cumulative number of adopters at \(t\)

  • \(p\) = probability of an initial purchase at time 0 (when \(Y(0) = 0\)) (also known as innovators importance).

  • \(\frac{q}{m} Y(t)\) = pressure of prior adopters on imitators

  • \(m\) = number of initial purchases before any replacement purchases (i.e., market size)

  • \(F(t)\) = cumulative fraction of adopters at time \(t\)

  • \(f(t)\) = likelihood of purchase at time \(t\)

Rearrange the formula to get the likelihood of purchase at time \(t\)

\[ f(t) = (p + q F(t) ) [1 - F(t)] \]

The number of adoptions at time \(t\) is

\[ S(t) = mf(t) = pm + (q - p) Y(t) - \frac{q}{m} Y^2(t) \]

then Bass solves the differential equation:

\[ dt = \frac{dF}{p + (q - p) F - qF^2} \]

to obtain cumulative adoption at time \(t\)

\[ F(t) = \frac{1 - e^{-( p + q)t}}{q + (q/p) e^{-( p + q)t}} \]

Hence, the cumulative number of adopters is

\[ Y(t) = m \frac{1 - e^{-( p + q)t}}{q + (q/p) e^{-( p + q)t}} \]

Rewriting the number of adoptions at time \(t\)

\[ S_t = a + bY_{t-1} + c Y^2_{t-1}, t = 2, 3, \dots \]

where

  • \(S_t\) = sales at time \(t\)

  • \(Y_{t-1}\) = cumulative sales through period \(t-1\)

  • \(a = p \times m\)

  • \(b = q - p\)

  • \(c = - q /m\)

Equivalently,

\[ p = a/m \\ q = -cm \\ m = (-b \pm (b^2 - 4 ac)^{1/2})/2c \]

Strengths

  • Good fit to the S-shaped curve (thank to the quadratic term)

  • Appealing interpretations:

    • \(p\) = coefficient of innovation (i.e., spontaneous rate of adoption in the population) or external influence (e.g., mass -media communications)

    • \(q\) = coefficient of imitation (i.e., effect of prior cumulative adopters on adoption) or internal influence (e.g., interpersonal communication influence from prior adopters).

  • Good application: time (\(t\)) or magnitude (\(S(t)\)) of peak sales.

\[ t^* = \frac{1}{p + q} \times \ln (\frac{q}{p}) \\ S(t)^* = m \times \frac{(p + q)^2}{4q} \]

  • Incorporated prior literature

    • If \(p =0\), the Bass model is a logistic diffusion function (driven only be imitation adoption)

    • If \(q = 0\), the Bass model is an exponential function (driven only innovation adoption)

Limitations

  • Bass requires 2 most important events that we want to predict in the first place: takeoff and slowdown to have stable estimates.

  • Unstable estimates after incorporating new observations.

  • Do not directly account for marketing mix variables (price, promotion), but indirectly capture by \(m, p\)

  • Assumes product definition is static (no growth or changes in product as time progresses)

  • Using OLS which can cause

    • Multicollinearity between \(Y_{t-1}, Y^2_{t-1}\) (making the estimates unstable)

    • Do not estimate the SE for \(p, q, m\)

    • Time interval bias (model uses discrete time series data to estimate a continuous model)

  • Hard to determine starting and ending points of the the sales time.

    • Supposedly, we need to use first adoptions of new product as sales (\(S_t\)), but data could not capture this, only both first purchases and repurchases

    • Sales should start from the first year of commercialization, but usually we only have reports when products are selling well already

    • No clear stopping rule for the time interval.

Improvements

  • Incorporating marketing mix

    • Price: affect market potential (\(m\)) and probability of adoption (\(P(t)\)) and heterogeneous across products

    • Advertising

    • Distribution: 2 adoption processes: retailer and consumer, where number of retailers who affect determine the market potential \(m\) for consumers

(Bass, Krishnan, and Jain 1994) incorporate both price and promotion to the Generalized Bass model

\[ \frac{f(t)}{1 - F(t)} = (p + q F(t) )x(t) \]

where \(x(t)\) is the current marketing effort (sum of advertising and price) on the conditional probability of product adoption at time \(t\) such that

\[ x(t) = 1 + \beta_1 \frac{\Delta P(t)}{P(t-1)} + \beta_2 \frac{\Delta A(t)}{A(t-1)} \]

where

  • \(\Delta P(t) = P(t) - P(t-1)\) rate of changes in price

  • \(\Delta A(t) = A(t) - A(t-1)\) rate of changes in advertising

When prices and advertising remain constant, GB model reduces to Bass model. But it seems like they only stop at 2 variables (not all marketing mix variables or macro and micro econ variables - income changes).

  • Incorporate supply restrictions

    • Include another stage between potential adopter to adopters which is waiting applicants.

\[ \frac{d A(t)}{dt} = [p + \frac{q_1}{m}A(t) + \frac{q_2}{m} N(t)][ m - A(t) - N(t) ] - c(t) A(t) \\ = \text{[Waiting population + Adopters] - conversion rate of applicants to adopters}\\ \]

and

\(\frac{d N(t)}{dt} = c(t) A(t)\)

where

  • \(d(A)/dt\) is the rate of changes of waiting applicants

  • \(c(t)\) is the supply coefficient

  • the second equation is the impact of supply restrictions on adoption rate

The growth of new applicants is

\[ \frac{d Z(t)}{dt} = \frac{d A(t)}{dt} + \frac{dN(t)}{dt} \\ = (p + \frac{q_1}{m} A(t) + \frac{q_2}{m} N(t) ) (m - A(t) - N(t)) \]

To incorporate waiting applicants abandoning their adoption decision after some time see (Ho, Savin, and Terwiesch 2002)

  • Incorporate competitive effects

    • Instead of using product category as the unit of analysis, we can model at the brand level (different brand might have different rate of diffusion).

    • A new brand can

      • increase the entire market potential (\(m\)) (by increased promotion and product variety)

      • compete in the existing market potential (interfere the diffusion process of other brands)

    • Diffusion depends on the order of entry and competition.

  • Incorporate complementary effects

    • In market that has indirect network externalities, co-diffusion exists and asymmetric
  • Incorporate technological generations for successive generations of the same product (i.e., substitution effects).

\[ S_1(t) = m_1F_1(t) - m_1 F_1(t) F_2(t - r_2) \]

where \(r_2\) is the introduction time of the next-generation product.

\[ S_2(t) = F_2(t- r_2) [m_2 + F_1(t) m_1] \]

where

  • \(S_i(t)\) = sales of generation \(i\)

  • \(F_i(t)\) = fraction of adoption for each generation

  • \(m_i\) = market potential for each generation

Leapfrogging behavior is possible (i.e., skip a generation to buy the next one) (Mahajan and Muller 1996)

\[ \frac{d F(t)}{dt} = [ p + q F(t)^\delta][ 1 - F(t)] \]

where \(\delta\) is the nonuniform influence

  • when \(\delta = 1\), the model becomes the Bass model

  • When \(\delta \in [0,1]\), means high initial coefficient of imitation,

  • When \(\delta >1\), means delay in influence -> lower and later peak.

Different adopters could influence later adopters differently (people who adopted more recently are more vocal) (Sharma and Bhargava 1994)

  • Incorporate replacement and mufti-unit purchases

(Balasubramanian and Kamakura 1989)

\[ y(t) = [a + bX(t)][\alpha \text{Population}(t) P^\beta (t) - X(t)] + r(t) + e(t) \]

where

  • \(y(t)\) = sales

  • \(P(t)\) = price index

  • \(X(t)\) = total units in use at the beginning of year \(t\) with dead units are replaced already

  • \(r(t)\) = number o units that have died or need replacement at year \(t\)

  • \(a\) = coefficient of innovation

  • \(b\) = coefficient imitation

  • \(\beta\) = price change effect on ultimate penetration

  • \(\alpha\) = ultimate penetration (price is at its original level)

(Steffens 2003) models multiple units purchase by a single household.

  • Incorporate trail-repeat purchases

  • Incorporate variations across countries

Evaluation:

  • All of the improvements still rest on the assumption of one driving mechanism: knowledge dispersion through WOM.

Improvements in estimation

  • MLE: avoid time-interval bias, but underestimates the SE (Schmittlein and Mahajan 1982)

  • Non linear least squares: (V. Srinivasan and Mason 1986) need lots of obs

    • Estimates are more flexible

    • No time-interval bias

    • valid SE

  • Hierarchical Bayesian method

    • Incorporate parameter updating

    • Problem with definition of similar products (fixed by (Bayus 1993) with product segmentation scheme)

  • Adaptive techniques: stochastic techniques (parameter vary over time) ((J. Xie et al. 1997)augmented Kalman filter)

  • Genetic algorithms:

    • can find global optimum

    • better estimate (less bias).

Alternative models of diffusion

Modeling the turning points in diffusion

36.2.1.2 (Bass 1969)

Assumption:

  • The timing of a consumer’s initial purchase is correlated with the number of previous

  • This paper looks at new class of products (not new brands or new models of older products)

  • Focus on infrequently purchased products

Theory of Adoption and Diffusion

  • Innovators: adopt independently (regardless of others’ opinions): pressure to adopt does not increase with the growth of the adoption.

  • Imitators (include early adopters, early majority, late majority): adoption depends on the timing of adoption (i.e., influenced by the decisions of others to adopt.

  • Laggards

“The probability that an initial purchase will be made at \(T\) given that no purchase has yet been made is a linear function of the number of previous buyers” (p. 216)

\[ P(T) = p + \frac{q}{m} Y(T) \]

where \(p\) and \(q/m\) are constants

\(Y(T)\) is the number of previous buyers.

When \(Y(T) = 0\), \(p\) represents the probability of an initial purchase at \(T = 0\)

\((q/m) Y(T)\) is the pressures on imitators to adopt.

Model Assumptions:

36.2.2 Discussion

36.2.2.1 (Sood, James, and Tellis 2009)

  • Functional regression

  • Contributions:

    • Theoretically sound (integrate info across categorizes)

    • Augmented Functional regression outperforms existing models

    • Product-specific effects are more helpful in predicting penetration than country-specific effects.

  • They use yearly cumulative penetration of each category as the unit of analysis (i.e., curve/ function).

  • 3 functional data analysis techniques:

    • Functional principal components

    • functional regression

    • functional cluster analysis

  • To treat discrete intervals: use smoothing spline to generate continuous smooth curves

  • Even though the spline approach requires a lot of data to smooth, other appearances to create smoothness are still available. Hence, you can still use function regression and or cluster with 2 or 3 time points.

  • Advantage s of functional regression:

    • incorporate info from other products

    • nonparametric fitting procedure

    • uses the functional nature of the penetration curves.

  • Predictions on: number of years to take off, peak marginal penetration and the level of peak marginal penetration

  • Good: tell a story from simple to more sophisticated model to justify their improvements in the paper.

  • 2 dimensions that are not captured by simple extrapolation models:

    • info from prior history of the new product

    • intrinsic info across products and countries.

  • Classic Bass model ignores:

    • other categories (fixed by meta-bass and augmented meta-bass)

    • uses parametric methods.

  • Questions:

    • Technically could redo the analysis with new dataset (including 2009 till now) to see the out of sample performance.

    • No hypothesis, just model and probable explanation

    • Use only curves under the same category to predict the new product (not all categories).

36.2.2.2 (Appel, Libai, and Muller 2019)

  • Growth, Popularity and the Long Tail: Evidence from Digital Markets

  • part of MSI’s working paper series and MSI insights

  • Context: digitized markets (long-tail markets)

  • Most popular products do have S-shaped curve, but lower-popularity products exponential-like decline (“slide”) or a combination of slide and bell (S&B) are more common.

  • Shortcomings of previous research:

    • Pro-innovation bias: success correlates with importance in the new product development research
  • Data: SourceForge (exclude inactive and less than 200 downloads): 5 years with high Gini coefficient - 0.96 (i.e., high concentration).

  • Dominant patterns:

    • A bell-shaped pattern: bell (popular products)

      • Caveat in the movie market: popular products decline over time.
    • An exponential-like decline beginning at launch: slide

    • Combination of the first 2: S&B

  • Proposed model: inception model (inception effect = heightened external growth).

  • Long-tail market:

    • Supply side: low cost of inventory, stocking, efficient delivery, and low cost of new products development.

    • Demand-side: easy to search, recommendation system, social networks and online communities.

  • Popularity = extent of demand = number of downloads.

  • The shape of new product growth: previous literature says S-shaped

  • Non-S-shaped markets:

    • r-shaped cumulative curve: because of

      • Large budget for promotion: movies

      • Pre-launch buzz: on social media

  • The role of popularity on the shape of growth: was ignored in the literature

  • Free and Open-Source Software (FOSS)

  • Data Analysis:

    • Stage 1: To facilitate comparison, scale pattern to a (0,1) by dividing each observation by the total sum of downloads, and smooth the graph using Hodrick-Prescott filter

    • Stage 2: Use peaks-and-troughs algorithm for the classification

  • Descriptive: the S-shaped curve is representative for more popular products, while for those that are not as popular, we have a blend of S&B and slide as well.

  • Try to observe the same pattern with smartphone app download (data provided by Mobility - an anonymous app providers for businesses)

  • Drivers of Multi-pattern Growth

    • Analogy to movies (characterized by an exponential decline): not similar because

      • different product types (utilitarian vs. entertainment)

      • Different pattern exhibited by popular and unpopular: while in movies the exponential decline is from blockbuster, and sleepers has a bell shape, under this dataset, less popular product has the exponential decline, while the popular products are bell-shaped.

    • Analogy to supermarkets: not good because FDP is affected by social influence, supermarkets are usually under large investments and not much social influence.

    • The inception alternative: 2 influences of new product growth

      • Internal: from previous adopters

      • External (not from previous adopters): marketing mix, social media posts, recommendation, expert opinions, influencers. Expected to stronger early on and decay. (i.e., inception effect - external influence as a function of time with an initial external influence parameter \(p(t) = pe^{\delta t}\))

  • The relationship between inception and popularity: The higher the product’s popularity, the lower the share of adoptions due to the inception effects (i.e., products with high initial investment that failed to reach critical is less popular).

  • Inception is typically a necessary but not sufficient condition to reach popularity.

36.2.2.3 (Tellis et al. 2020)

  • No awards (nominated only)

  • Emotion is more effective than information

  • brand hurts, but branding is used a lot

  • surprise and humor are good, but videos don’t use

  • Limitation: Because these emotions are rare, maybe that why they are effective. But if everyone starts using these tactics, maybe that they wont’ work anymore.

36.2.2.4 (Chandrasekaran, Tellis, and James 2020)

  • Was rejected 5 times.

  • Leapfrogging, Cannibalization, and survival during disruptive technological change

  • 2 types of dilemma when it comes to new technology:

    • Incumbent: invest in new technology or old or both

    • Entrant: target niche or mass.

    • Solution: relation between new technology and old one (i.e., high rate of disengagement - cannibalization or low rate of disengagement- coexistence)

  • Data:

    • Successive technology penetration across multiple countries and years

    • Sales of contemporaneous pair across multiples countries

    • Case analyses

  • “Disruption occurs if the incumbent focuses on the old technology to the exclusion of the new one” (p. 4)

  • Definitions:

    • Successive/New technology: not new version/generations of the same product

    • Cannibalization: “the extent to which the successive technology”eats” into real or potential sales (or penetration) of the old technology due to substitution.”(p. 5)

    • Rate of disengagement \(F_{12}\): (account for partial substitution)

    • Adopter segments for a new successive technology:

      • Leapfroggers: adopt new, but would never have adopted the old

      • Switchers: Adopted old, but switch to new once it’s introduced

      • Opportunists: wait for the old, but end up with the new one.

      • Dual users: both technologies

    • Models: based on (J. A. Norton and Bass 1987)

\[ S_1 (t) = m_1 F_1(t) (1- F_{12}(t- \tau_2 + 1)) \\ S_2 (t) = F_2(T- \tau_2 + 1) (m_2 + m_1 F_1(t)) \]

where

  • \(S_i(t)\) = penetration of technology \(i\) in period \(t\)
  • \(m_1\) = long-run penetration for technology 1
  • \(m_1 + m_2\) = long-run penetration for technology 2

The fraction of all potential technology_g consumers for each technology (g = technology 1 or 2)

\[ F_g(t) = \frac{p_g(1 - e^{-(p_g + q_g)^t})}{p_g + q_g e^{-(p_g + q_g)t}} \]

where

  • \(t \ge 0\)

  • \(g = 1, 2\)

  • \(p\) = innovation coefficient

  • \(q\) = imitation coefficient

  • \(p_{12}, q_{12}\) = disengagement coefficients

  • \(F_1, F_2, F_{12}\) = adoption rate of technology 1, technology 2, and disengagement rate at which technology 1 customers abandon to get technology 2

Model contributions:

  • Model the adoption rate of technology 2 different from disengagement rate of technology 1 (\(F_2 \neq F_{12}\))

  • Varying \(p, q\) (for different technologies)

  • \(F_1\) has the same function form as \(F_1, F_2\) (because it fits the data well, and reduces to previous model which matches previous literature)

  • Model can be applied to both generational and technology diffusion

Model Estimation

Using nonlinear least squares to estimate the parameters that that minimize

\[ \sum_{i = 1}^n (s_{i1} - m_1 F_1(t_i)) (1 - F_{12} (t_i - \tau_2 + 1))^2 \\ + \sum_{i=1}^n (s_{i2} - F_2 (t_i - \tau_2 + 1)(m_2 + m_1F_1(t_i)))^2 \]

Segments of adopters

\[ S_2(t) = L_2(t) + DU_2(t) + SW_2(t) + O_2(t) \]

while

\[ S_1(t) = L_1(t) - CAN_2(t) = L_1(t) - (SW_2(t) + O_2(t)) \]

where

  • \(SW\) = switchers

  • \(O\) = Opportunists

  • \(CAN\) = Canalization

  • \(L\) = Leapfroggers

  • \(DU\) = dual -users

Market growth segment = sum(leapfroggers, dual users)

Cannibalization = sum(switchers, opportunists).

36.2.2.5 (Prins and Verhoef 2007) Marketing effects on adoption timing

  • Studies the effects of direct marketing and mass marketing on adoption timing (in the context of a new e-service among existing customers)

  • Data: 6k customers of a Dutch telecom operator over 25 months

  • Findings:

    • advertising shortens the time to adoption (including those by competitors)

    • Mass marketing has a greater effect on loyal customers (compared direct marketing)

  • Related literature:

    • Adoption

    • customer management

  • Adoption timing is defined as “the time between the introduction and the adoption of the new service” (p. 170) following (Jan-Benedict E. M. Steenkamp and Gielens 2003)

  • Switchers to competitive services are considered as non-adopters (even if they adopt comeptitor’s new service). It’s valid when the focus is on the adoption of the folca company’s new service among existing customers.

  • (Donkers, Franses, and Verhoef 2003) demonstrates that if oversampling is not accompanied by stratfied sampling on the independent variables, it should not affect the parameter estimates or SE for are event in binnary choice models.

  • Meausres of Time to adoption: For each tiem period \(t\), a customer can either adopt the new serive or not. The time to adoption for each customer is the time elasped in \(t\) since the intro of the service. Dependent vairable = indivudal time to adoption.

References

Agarwal, Rajshree, and Barry L. Bayus. 2002. “The Market Evolution and Sales Takeoff of Product Innovations.” Management Science 48 (8): 1024–41. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.48.8.1024.167.
Appel, Gil, Barak Libai, and Eitan Muller. 2019. “Growth, Popularity, and the Long Tail: Evidence from Digital Markets.” SSRN Electronic Journal. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3464393.
Balasubramanian, Siva K., and Wagner A. Kamakura. 1989. “Measuring Consumer Attitudes Toward the Marketplace with Tailored Interviews.” Journal of Marketing Research 26 (3): 311. https://doi.org/10.2307/3172903.
Bass, Frank M. 1969. “A New Product Growth for Model Consumer Durables.” Management Science 15 (5): 215–27. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.15.5.215.
Bass, Frank M., Trichy V. Krishnan, and Dipak C. Jain. 1994. “Why the Bass Model Fits Without Decision Variables.” Marketing Science 13 (3): 203–23. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.13.3.203.
Bayus, Barry L. 1993. “The Targeted Marketing of Consumer Durables.” Journal of Direct Marketing 7 (4): 4–13. https://doi.org/10.1002/dir.4000070403.
Bemmaor, Albert C. 1984. “Testing Alternative Econometric Models on the Existence of Advertising Threshold Effect.” Journal of Marketing Research 21 (3): 298. https://doi.org/10.2307/3151606.
Bronnenberg, Bart J., and Carl F. Mela. 2004. “Market Roll-Out and Retailer Adoption for New Brands.” Marketing Science 23 (4): 500–518. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1040.0072.
Bulte, Christophe Van den, and Gary L. Lilien. 2001. “Medical Innovation Revisited: Social Contagion Versus Marketing Effort.” American Journal of Sociology 106 (5): 1409–35. https://doi.org/10.1086/320819.
Chandrasekaran, Deepa, and Gerard J. Tellis. 2007. “A Critical Review of Marketing Research on Diffusion of New Products.” In, 39–80. Emerald Group Publishing Limited. https://doi.org/10.1108/s1548-6435(2007)0000003006.
Chandrasekaran, Deepa, Gerard J. Tellis, and Gareth M. James. 2020. “Leapfrogging, Cannibalization, and Survival During Disruptive Technological Change: The Critical Role of Rate of Disengagement.” Journal of Marketing, December, 002224292096791. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022242920967912.
Chatterjee, Rabik Ar, and Jehoshua Eliashberg. 1990. “The Innovation Diffusion Process in a Heterogeneous Population: A Micromodeling Approach.” Management Science 36 (9): 1057–79. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.36.9.1057.
Dekimpe, Marnik G., Philip M. Parker, and Miklos Sarvary. 2000. “Global Diffusion of Technological Innovations: A Coupled-Hazard Approach.” Journal of Marketing Research 37 (1): 47–59. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.37.1.47.18722.
Donkers, Bas, Philip Hans Franses, and Peter C. Verhoef. 2003. “Selective Sampling for Binary Choice Models.” Journal of Marketing Research 40 (4): 492–97. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkr.40.4.492.19395.
Easingwood, Christopher J., Vijay Mahajan, and Eitan Muller. 1983. “A Nonuniform Influence Innovation Diffusion Model of New Product Acceptance.” Marketing Science 2 (3): 273–95. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.2.3.273.
Elberse, Anita, and Jehoshua Eliashberg. 2003. “Demand and Supply Dynamics for Sequentially Released Products in International Markets: The Case of Motion Pictures.” Marketing Science 22 (3): 329–54. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.22.3.329.17740.
Eliashberg, Jehoshua, Jedid-Jah Jonker, Mohanbir S. Sawhney, and Berend Wierenga. 2000. “MOVIEMOD: An Implementable Decision-Support System for Prerelease Market Evaluation of Motion Pictures.” Marketing Science 19 (3): 226–43. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.19.3.226.11796.
Eliashberg, Jehoshua, and Mohanbir S. Sawhney. 1994. “Modeling Goes to Hollywood: Predicting Individual Differences in Movie Enjoyment.” Management Science 40 (9): 1151–73. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.40.9.1151.
Garber, Tal, Jacob Goldenberg, Barak Libai, and Eitan Muller. 2004. “From Density to Destiny: Using Spatial Dimension of Sales Data for Early Prediction of New Product Success.” Marketing Science 23 (3): 419–28. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1040.0051.
Goldenberg, Jacob, Barak Libai, and Eitan Muller. 2001. “Talk of the Network: A Complex Systems Look at the Underlying Process of Word-of-Mouth.” Marketing Letters 12 (3): 211–23.
———. 1997. “Will It Ever Fly? Modeling the Takeoff of Really New Consumer Durables.” Marketing Science 16 (3): 256–70. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.16.3.256.
———. 1998. “Beyond Diffusion: An Affordability Model of the Growth of New Consumer Durables.” Journal of Forecasting 17 (3-4): 259–80. https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1099-131x(199806/07)17:3/4<259::aid-for696>3.0.co;2-t.
———. 2004. “Growing, Growing, Gone: Cascades, Diffusion, and Turning Points in the Product Life Cycle.” Marketing Science 23 (2): 207–18. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1040.0057.
Ho, Teck-Hua, Sergei Savin, and Christian Terwiesch. 2002. “Managing Demand and Sales Dynamics in New Product Diffusion Under Supply Constraint.” Management Science 48 (2): 187–206. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.48.2.187.257.
Horsky, Dan. 1990. “A Diffusion Model Incorporating Product Benefits, Price, Income and Information.” Marketing Science 9 (4): 342–65. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.9.4.342.
Karshenas, Massoud, and Paul L. Stoneman. 1993. “Rank, Stock, Order, and Epidemic Effects in the Diffusion of New Process Technologies: An Empirical Model.” The RAND Journal of Economics 24 (4): 503. https://doi.org/10.2307/2555742.
Lee, Jonathan, Peter Boatwright, and Wagner A. Kamakura. 2003. “A Bayesian Model for Prelaunch Sales Forecasting of Recorded Music.” Management Science 49 (2): 179–96. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.49.2.179.12744.
Mahajan, Vijay, and Eitan Muller. 1996. “Timing, Diffusion, and Substitution of Successive Generations of Technological Innovations: The IBM Mainframe Case.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 51 (2): 109–32. https://doi.org/10.1016/0040-1625(95)00225-1.
Mahajan, Vijay, and Robert A. Peterson. 1978. “Innovation Diffusion in a Dynamic Potential Adopter Population.” Management Science 24 (15): 1589–97. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.24.15.1589.
———. 1979. “Integrating Time and Space in Technological Substitution Models.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 14 (3): 231–41. https://doi.org/10.1016/0040-1625(79)90079-9.
Moe, Wendy W., and Peter S. Fader. 2002. “Fast-Track: Article Using Advance Purchase Orders to Forecast New Product Sales.” Marketing Science 21 (3): 347–64. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.21.3.347.138.
Norton, John A., and Frank M. Bass. 1987. “A Diffusion Theory Model of Adoption and Substitution for Successive Generations of High-Technology Products.” Management Science 33 (9): 1069–86. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.33.9.1069.
Oren, Shmuel S., and Rick G. Schwartz. 1988. “Diffusion of New Products in Risk-Sensitive Markets.” Journal of Forecasting 7 (4): 273–87. https://doi.org/10.1002/for.3980070407.
Prins, Remco, and Peter C. Verhoef. 2007. “Marketing Communication Drivers of Adoption Timing of a New E-Service Among Existing Customers.” Journal of Marketing 71 (2): 169–83. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkg.71.2.169.
Redmond, William H. 2003. “Diffusion at Sub-National Levels: A Regional Analysis of New Product Growth.” Journal of Product Innovation Management 11 (3): 201–12. https://doi.org/10.1111/1540-5885.1130201.
Roberts, John H., and Glen L. Urban. 1988. “Modeling Multiattribute Utility, Risk, and Belief Dynamics for New Consumer Durable Brand Choice.” Management Science 34 (2): 167–85. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.34.2.167.
Schmittlein, David C., and Vijay Mahajan. 1982. “Maximum Likelihood Estimation for an Innovation Diffusion Model of New Product Acceptance.” Marketing Science 1 (1): 57–78. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1.1.57.
Sharma, Praveen, and S. C. Bhargava. 1994. “A Non-Homogeneous Non-Uniform Influence Model of Innovation Diffusion.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 46 (3): 279–88. https://doi.org/10.1016/0040-1625(94)90006-x.
Sinha, Rajiv K., and Murali Chandrashekaran. 1992. “A Split Hazard Model for Analyzing the Diffusion of Innovations.” Journal of Marketing Research 29 (1): 116. https://doi.org/10.2307/3172497.
Song, Inseong, and Pradeep K. Chintagunta. 2003b. “A Micromodel of New Product Adoption with Heterogeneous and Forward-Looking Consumers: Application to the Digital Camera Category.” Quantitative Marketing and Economics 1 (4): 371–407. https://doi.org/10.1023/b:qmec.0000004843.41279.f3.
Sood, Ashish, Gareth M. James, and Gerard J. Tellis. 2009. “Functional Regression: A New Model for Predicting Market Penetration of New Products.” Marketing Science 28 (1): 36–51. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1080.0382.
Srinivasan, V., and Charlotte H. Mason. 1986. “Technical NoteNonlinear Least Squares Estimation of New Product Diffusion Models.” Marketing Science 5 (2): 169–78. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.5.2.169.
Steenkamp, Jan-Benedict E. M., and Katrijn Gielens. 2003. “Consumer and Market Drivers of the Trial Probability of New Consumer Packaged Goods.” Journal of Consumer Research 30 (3): 368–84. https://doi.org/10.1086/378615.
Steffens, Paul R. 2003. “A Model of Multiple-Unit Ownership as a Diffusion Process.” Technological Forecasting and Social Change 70 (9): 901–17. https://doi.org/10.1016/s0040-1625(02)00398-0.
Stremersch, Stefan, and Gerard J. Tellis. 2004. “Understanding and Managing International Growth of New Products.” International Journal of Research in Marketing 21 (4): 421–38. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijresmar.2004.07.001.
———. 2020. “What Drives Virality (Sharing, Spread) of YouTube Video Ads: Emotion Vs Brand Prominence and Information.” SSRN Electronic Journal. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3583613.
Tellis, Gerard J., Stefan Stremersch, and Eden Yin. 2003. “The International Takeoff of New Products: The Role of Economics, Culture, and Country Innovativeness.” Marketing Science 22 (2): 188–208. https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.22.2.188.16041.
Xie, Jinhong, X. Michael Song, Marvin Sirbu, and Qiong Wang. 1997. “Kalman Filter Estimation of New Product Diffusion Models.” Journal of Marketing Research 34 (3): 378. https://doi.org/10.2307/3151900.