21.19 Marketing Resource Allocation Models

This section is based on (Mantrala, Sinha, and Zoltners 1992)

21.19.1 Case study 1

Concave sales response function

  • Optimal vs. proportional at different investment levels
  • Profit maximization perspective of aggregate function

\[ s_i = k_i (1- e^{-b_i x_i}) \]

where

  • \(s_i\) = current-period sales response (dollars / period)
  • \(x_i\) = amount of resource allocated to submarket i
  • \(b_i\) = rate at which sales approach saturation
  • \(k_i\) = sales potential

Allocation functions

  • Fixed proportion

    • \(R_i\) = Investment level (dollars/period)

    • \(w_i\) = fixed proportion or weights

\[ \hat{x}_i = w_i R; \\ \sum_{t=1}^2 w_t = 1; 0 < w_t < 1 \]

  • Informed allocator

    • optimal allocations via marginal analysis (maximize profits)

\[ max C = m \sum_{i = 1}^2 k_i (1- e^{-b_i x_i}) \\ x_1 + x_2 \le R; x_i \ge 0 \text{ for } i = 1,2 \\ x_1 = \frac{1}{(b_1 + b_2)(b_2 R + \ln(\frac{k_1b_1}{k_2b_2})} \\ x_2 = \frac{1}{(b_1 + b_2)(b_2 R + \ln(\frac{k_2b_2}{k_1b_1})} \]

21.19.2 Case study 2

S-shaped sales response function:

  • Optimal vs. proportional at different investment levels
  • Profit maximization perspective of aggregate function

21.19.3 Case study 3

Quadratic-form stochastic response function

  • Optimal allocation only with risk averse and risk neutral investors.

References

Mantrala, Murali K., Prabhakant Sinha, and Andris A. Zoltners. 1992. “Impact of Resource Allocation Rules on Marketing Investment-Level Decisions and Profitability.” Journal of Marketing Research 29 (2): 162. https://doi.org/10.2307/3172567.