Chapter 5 Optimal individual choices

5.1 The Expected Utility framework

5.1.1 VNM theory

Describing the way economic agent make a choice between two possibilities or asset in an uncertain world is an important part of micro-economics. For a classical survey see Kreps (2018).

Preferences are defined as a relationship between economic outcomes X and Y where either :

  • X is preferred to Y, (XY=
  • the agent is indifferent between X and Y (XY)
  • the agent doesn’t know

Von Neumann and Morgenstern (1947) show that under reasonable assumptions on preferences such as:

  • Completeness: (X,Y):XYorXYorXY

  • Continuity: (X,Y,Z):XYZp[0,1]|YpX+(1p)Z

  • Transitivity: (X,Y,Z):XYandYZXZ

  • Independence: For any N and p(0,1], LMiffpL+(1p)NpM+(1p)N

then preferences can be represented by the expectation of a utility function u under some probability measure.

Hence, When the set of outcome is in R then U can be shown to be increasing and concave. Further regularity conditions such as the Inada conditions might be added to ensure that

In a situation where investors want to discriminate among possible portfolio outcomes or different option profile, they should hence choose argsup˜VTE(U(˜VT))

5.1.2 Risk aversion and risk premia,

Let ˜VT the final wealth and ˉVTE(˜VT)

Let U(~VT)U(¯VT)+(~VT¯VT)U(¯VT)+12(~VT¯VT)2U

Since U is concave one has \mathbb{E}\left(U\left(\tilde{V_{T}}\right)\right)\leq U\left(\bar{V_{T}}\right) As a result, when U is continuous, there exists a positive value \pi such that \mathbb{E}\left(U\left(\tilde{V_{T}}\right)\right)=U\left(\bar{V_{T}}-\pi\right)

\pi is called the risk premia and V_{eq}\equiv \bar{V_{T}}-\pi is called the certainty equivalent of \tilde{V_{T}} associated to U.

For small risks, the risk premia can be approximated by a first order expansion of U:

U\left(\bar{V_{T}}-\pi\right)=U\left(\bar{V_{T}}\right)-\pi U'\left(\bar{V_{T}}\right)

and hence \pi\approx\frac{\lambda}{2}\sigma_{V}^{2}

where \lambda_{abs}\equiv-\frac{U''}{U'} is called the local Absolute Risk Aversion. The Relative Risk Aversion is defined by \lambda_{rel}=\lambda_{abs}\times V

Example 5.1 (Constant Absolute Risk Aversion) U(x)=-exp(-\lambda x) where \lambda>0 is the absolute risk aversion. The corresponding behavior is then described by the fact that x_0 can be seen as some kind of “target wealth”. When x<<x_0, then U is quasi risk neutral and when x>>x_O the relative risk aversion becomes large. \begin{align} \frac{\Delta U}{U} &=-\lambda\Delta x \\ & = \frac{\Delta x}{x_0} \end{align}

::: example name =“Constant Relative Risk Aversion”

U\left(x\right)=\left\{ \begin{array}{c} \frac{x^{1-a}-1}{1-a}\;a\geq0,a\neq1\\ ln\left(x\right)\;a=1 \end{array}\right. where a is the Absolute Risk Aversion. In that case:

\begin{align} \frac{\Delta U}{U} &=-\lambda\Delta x \\ & = \frac{\Delta x}{x_0} \end{align}

The corresponding behavior is then described by the fact that x_0 can be seen as some kind of “target wealth”. When x<<x_0, then U is quasi risk neutral and when x>>x_O the relative risk aversion becomes large.

\frac{\Delta U}{U} =(1-a)\frac{\Delta x}{x} This corresponds to a behavior with no target satisfactory wealth. Whichever the level of wealth, x% return provides the exact same increase of Utility. :::

5.2 Mean-variance choices

5.2.1 Wealth equation

Consider a situation where, between date 0 and date 1, your initial wealth w has to be invested into:

  • n risky assets with value S^i_t such that the random expected return \mu^i \quad | \quad S^i_1=S^i_0\times(1+\mu^i) is described as a random variable with mean \mu and covariance matrix \Sigma. \mu is often referred to as the expected return of that asset,
  • a non risky asset which return is known beforehand to be equal to R. R is also the cost of borrowing money which can be done without constraint.

Let \alpha be the proportion of w invested into the risky assets. Let \alpha_0=1-\sum_i \alpha_i the amount invested or borrowed to the bank. The final (random) wealth yields \tilde{W}=w\times(1+R+\alpha'(\tilde{\mu}-R\mathbb I_n))

Let us define the excess returns as \tilde{\pi_i}\equiv\tilde{\mu_i}-R and the excess return of the porfolio as \tilde{\pi}(\alpha) \equiv \frac{\tilde{W}}{w}-(1+R). The following relationship holds:

\begin{equation} \tilde{\pi}(\alpha)=\alpha' \tilde{\pi} \tag{5.1} \end{equation}

Equation (5.1) shows that the excess return of the portfolio is a linear function of the excess return of the risky asset. That linear relationship between excess return is a key structure to keep in mind. Relation between portfolio moments and risky asset moments follows:

  • \pi(\alpha)=\mathbb E(\alpha' \tilde{\pi})=\alpha'\bar{\pi}
  • Var(\tilde \pi(\alpha))=\mathbb E (\alpha'\tilde \pi \tilde \pi' \alpha )=\alpha'\Sigma\alpha

Definition 5.1 (Sharpe ratio) The Sharpe ratio of an asset with average Excess Return \pi and volatility \sigma is defined as the ratio of the two: \frac{\pi}{\sigma}.

5.2.2 Optimal portfolio

The optimal portfolio is the solution of the same maximisation equation

\begin{equation} u(w)=\underset{\alpha \in \mathbb R^n}{sup}E(U(\tilde W)) \tag{5.2} \end{equation}

For a CARA utility with Gaussian returns, equation (5.2) becomes:

\begin{equation} u(w)=\underset{\alpha \in \mathbb R^n}{sup}\alpha'\pi-\frac{\lambda}{2}\alpha'\Sigma\alpha \tag{5.3} \end{equation}

The optimisation program (5.3) has to be solved in \mathbb R^n. It can be done line by line as in Markowitz (1952) seminal paper but it makes the result difficult to read.

It is somewhat easier to differentiate directly in \mathbb R^n even if this requires prior knowledge of some ad-hoc rules. See Petersen, Pedersen, et al. (2008) for instance. One finds that:

\begin{equation} \bar \alpha=\frac{1}{\lambda}\Sigma^{-1}\pi \tag{5.4} \end{equation}

A variational proof:

Define an auxiliary function \phi_{y}^{\alpha}(\epsilon)=f(\alpha+\epsilon y) \alpha\;optimal\Longleftrightarrow\left.\frac{d\phi_{y}^{\alpha}(\epsilon)}{d\epsilon}\right|_{\epsilon=0}=0\;\forall y\in\mathbb{R}^{n} Practically: \begin{align*} f(\alpha+\epsilon y) & =(\alpha+\epsilon y)'\pi-\frac{\lambda}{2}(\alpha+\epsilon y)'\Sigma(\alpha+\epsilon y)\\ & =cte+\left(y'\pi-\lambda\alpha'\Sigma y\right)\epsilon-\frac{\lambda}{2}y'\Sigma y\epsilon^{2}\\ \left.\frac{d\phi_{y}^{\alpha}(\epsilon)}{d\epsilon}\right|_{\epsilon=0} & =\left(\pi-\lambda\Sigma\alpha\right)'y \end{align*}

Since the above has to be equal to zero whatever y, QED.

Comments on equation (5.4):

  • The two fund separation theorem
  • role of correlation
  • exercise in dim 2.
  • formula without lending/borrowing
  • OSQP solver

References

Kreps, David. 2018. Notes on the Theory of Choice. Routledge.
Markowitz, Harry M. 1952. “Portfolio Selection.” Journal of Finance 7: 77–91.
Petersen, Kaare Brandt, Michael Syskind Pedersen, et al. 2008. “The Matrix Cookbook.” Technical University of Denmark 7 (15): 510.
Von Neumann, John, and Oskar Morgenstern. 1947. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton university press.